vignettes/GMSE.Rmd
GMSE.Rmd
Key words: adaptive management, conservation conflict, ecological modelling, game theory, management strategy evaluation
Many global natural resources, including the biodiversity on which critical ecosystem services depend, are in a state of severe decline (Dirzo et al. 2014; Hautier et al. 2015; Ceballos, Ehrlich, and Dirzo 2017; O’Connell 2017). Conservation of biodiversity can be complicated by the immediate need to use natural resources and land area for human livelihood, causing real or perceived conflicts between biodiversity conservation and agricultural production. This creates a challenging situation for the management of many natural resources (Redpath et al. 2015). Given increasing human population size (Crist, Mora, and Engelman 2017), the number and intensity of such conflicts are likely to increase into the twenty first century. Effective management tools are therefore needed for the long-term sustainable use of natural resources under the rising demand for food production (Fischer et al. 2017).
To effectively manage natural resources, an adaptive approach allows managers to iteratively update their models and respond flexibly to changing conditions (Keith et al. 2011). This approach is especially effective when considering multiple aspects of the social-ecological system being managed, including the dynamics of resources, monitoring, and the decision-making processes of stakeholders (Bunnefeld et al. 2011; Bunnefeld and Keane 2014). Management strategy evaluation (MSE) is a modelling framework, first developed in fisheries (e.g., Sainsbury, Punt, and Smith 2000; Polacheck et al. 1999; Smith, Sainsbury, and Stevens 1999; Moore et al. 2013), for simulating all of these aspects of resource management in a way that uniquely considers the uncertainties inherent to every stage of the management process (Bunnefeld et al. 2011; Punt et al. 2016). Nevertheless, MSE models developed hitherto have been limited in their ability to model human decision-making (Fulton et al. 2011; Dichmont and Fulton 2017); manager decisions are typically based on fixed rules, and user behaviour likewise remains fixed over time instead of dynamically responding to changing resource availability and management decisions (M. Schlüter et al. 2012; Melbourne-Thomas et al. 2017). Here we introduce generalised management strategy evaluation (GMSE), which incorporates a game-theoretic perspective to model the goal-oriented, dynamic decision-making processes of stakeholders.
The R package ‘GMSE’ is a flexible modelling tool to simulate key aspects of natural resource management. GMSE offers a range of parameters to simulate resource dynamics (primarily, but not necessarily biological populations) and management policy options, and includes genetic algorithms to dynamically model stakeholder (manager and user) decision-making. Genetic algorithms find adaptive solutions to any simulated conditions given stakeholder-specific goals (see The Genetic Algorithm of GMSE), allowing GMSE to model scenarios of conservation conflict.
GMSE allows researchers to address adaptive management questions in silico through simulation. Simulations can be parameterised with initial conditions derived from empirical populations of conservation interest to predict key social-ecological outcomes (e.g., resource extinction, agricultural yield) given uncertainty. The sensitivity of these outcomes to different management options (e.g., population target, policies available, observation methods, budget constraints, etc.) can thereby inform management decisions, even given competing management objectives caused by conservation conflict (e.g., Strand et al. 2012; Redpath et al. 2013; Sundt-Hansen et al. 2015; Pozo et al. 2017; Fox and Madsen 2017). Additionally, GMSE can be used to explore general questions concerning management theory such as the following: How is population persistence affected by management frequency or observation intensity? How does variation in user actions affect the distribution of resources or landscape properties? How do asymmetries in stakeholder influence (i.e., budgets) affect resource dynamics?
GMSE builds off of the MSE framework (Fig. 1). The function gmse
runs simulations
using four predefined individual-based submodels, which can be
parameterised to fit various case studies; more tailored submodels can
also be defined using the gmse_apply
function
(see Use of the gmse_apply function). By default,
GMSE models (1) a population of discrete resources (e.g., a managed
species) with individual traits (e.g., location, age) on a
spatially-explicit landscape and simulates resource birth, individual
movement between landscape cells, interaction with the landscape, and
death; the discrete nature of resources causes demographic
stochasticity, and therefore uncertainty. This sub-model is unique in
not relying on other sub-models because ecological dynamics can be
simulated in the absence of observation and management. (2) Observation
is modelled in one of three ways: resource counting on a subset of
landscape cells (e.g., Nuno, Bunnefeld, and Milner-Gulland
2013), marking and recapturing a fixed number of resources,
or counting resources across the whole landscape one set of landscape
cells at a time (during which resources might move). Sampling error from
all observation types generates a range of uncertainties that depend on
monitoring effort. (3) Managers analyse data collected from observations
to estimate resource abundance, then compare this estimate with their
pre-defined target abundance. Policy is developed by calling the genetic
algorithm (see below), which works within a manager’s constraints to
find costs for user actions on the resource (e.g., culling, scaring,
etc.) that minimise deviation from the target abundance, as informed by
the predicted consequences of each action on resource abundance and user
action histories. After a suitable policy is found, (4) users perform
actions that affect resources or landscape cells (e.g., culling, which
causes immediate resource death). Users respond to policy individually,
each calling the genetic algorithm to find actions that maximise their
own utilities (e.g., maximise resource use or landscape yield) within
their imposed constraints. Once each user has found an adaptive
strategy, user actions affect resources and landscape cells, feeding
back into the resource sub-model.
Consistent with the MSE approach (Bunnefeld et al. 2011), GMSE does not attempt to find optimal strategies or solutions for agents (stakeholders). Instead, a genetic algorithm is used to heuristically find strategies that reflect the individual objectives of each stakeholder in each time step (see The Genetic Algorithm of GMSE for details). Critically, all stakeholders involved in resource conservation are constrained in their decision-making; managing and using resources takes effort (e.g., time or money), and effort expended in developing or enforcing one policy (for managers) or performing one action (for users) will be effort not expendable elsewhere (Milner-Gulland 2011; Müller-Hansen et al. 2017; Maja Schlüter et al. 2017). In finding strategies, GMSE models this trade-off by setting a fixed budget for managers and users. Allocations from a manager’s budget can be used to increase the cost it takes a user to perform an action (i.e., ‘policy’), and allocations from a user’s budget can be used to perform the action at the cost set by the manager. Hence, stakeholders can have incomplete control over resource use and express competing management objectives, potentially resulting in conflict.
A single call of the genetic algorithm simulates the process of thinking and decision-making for one manager or user. In each new call of the genetic algorithm, a unique population of temporary manager or user strategies is initialised. In each iteration of the genetic algorithm, these strategies crossover and mutate; when this results in strategies that are over-budget, expenditures are iteratively decreased at random until budget constraints are satisfied. A fitness function then evaluates each strategy in the population, and a tournament is used to select the next iteration of strategies (Hamblin 2013). The genetic algorithm terminates when a minimum number of iterations has passed and the increase in the fitness of the fittest strategy between the current and previous iteration is below some threshold. The highest fitness strategy in the population then becomes the stakeholder’s new strategy.
Here we illustrate the usefulness of GMSE by considering the case study of a protected population of waterfowl that exploits agricultural land causing a conservation conflict with farmers (e.g., Fox and Madsen 2017; Mason et al. 2017; Tulloch, Nicol, and Bunnefeld 2017). Managers attempt to keep the abundance of waterfowl at a target level, while farmers attempt to minimise the damage inflicted on their crops (e.g., Madsen et al. 2017). Using GMSE, we can simulate waterfowl population dynamics, along with the continued monitoring and policy set by managers, and the actions that farmers take to protect their crop yields given the constraints of policy. We consider a population of waterfowl with an initial abundance and manager target abundance of 200, but whose carrying capacity is 2000. Waterfowl consume and destroy all crop yield upon arrival to a landscape cell. In each time step, waterfowl are observed on a random subset of cells, then managers extrapolate from density per cell to estimate total population size. Managers then use these estimates to set costs of culling and scaring waterfowl for five farmers (scaring is non-lethal, causing waterfowl to move to a random landscape cell). Farmers attempt to reduce the negative impact of waterfowl on the cropland that they own, working within the constraints of culling and scaring costs and their budget for performing these actions.
sim <- gmse(land_ownership = TRUE, stakeholders = 5, observe_type = 0,
res_death_K = 2000, manage_target = 1000, RESOURCE_ini = 200,
user_budget = 1000, manager_budget = 1000, res_consume = 1,
scaring = TRUE, plotting = FALSE);
## [1] "Initialising simulations ... "
## [1] "Generation 22 of 40"
Parameters in gmse
not listed are set to default values. By plotting the output with plot_gmse_results
,
simulation results can be interpreted visually (manager and user
decisions can also be interpreted using the plot_gmse_effort
function, see Example case study in GMSE and Advanced case study options for an expanded
example).
plot_gmse_results(sim_results = sim);
Fig. 2 shows the landscape broken down by resource position and farmer land ownership in the upper left and right hand panels, respectively. The waterfowl population fluctuates around the manager’s target size of 1000, but the manager’s estimate of population size deviates from its actual size due to observation uncertainty (compare black and blue lines in the middle left panel). Because the waterfowl have a direct negative effect on landscape yield, total landscape yield (orange line of the middle left panel), along with the yield of individual farmers (right middle panel), is low when waterfowl abundance is high, and vice versa.
Only the estimates of population size from the observation model are available to the manager, so policy change at any time step is driven primarily by the deviation of the currently estimated population size from the manager’s target and the actions of farmers in the previous time step. Hence, when the population size is estimated to be below (above) the manager’s target, the manager increases (decreases) the cost of culling and decreases (increases) the cost of scaring. Because the manager does not know in advance how farmers will react to policy change, they assume a proportional response in total actions with respect to a change in cost (e.g., doubling the cost of culling will decrease stakeholder culling by \(1/2\)). Farmers responding to policy are interested only in minimising waterfowl’s exploitation of their crops, so they will either cull or scare to remove the waterfowl from their land, depending on which option is more effective (i.e., cheaper). This is reflected in the bottom left versus right panels of Fig. 2; when managers decrease culling costs relative to scaring, farmers respond with more total culling, and vice versa. Farmer decisions then affect waterfowl distribution and abundance, impacting future crop yield and policy.
The function gmse_gui
opens GMSE
in a browser and allows simulations to be run for most gmse
parameter options
using the package ‘shiny’ (Chang et al.
2017). Figures from plot_gmse_results
and plot_gmse_effort
,
and tables from gmse_summary
are
provided as GUI output.
The function gmse_apply
allows
custom resource, observation, manager, or user sub-models to be
integrated into the GMSE framework (see Use of the
gmse_apply function, Advanced case study
options, and Fisheries example integrating
FLR). Any type of sub-model (e.g., numerical, individual-based) is
permitted by defining a function with appropriately specified inputs and
outputs; where custom functions are not provided, gmse_apply
runs
default GMSE sub-models used in gmse
. Any parameter
options available in gmse
or in custom
functions can be passed directly to gmse_apply
, thereby
allowing for high flexibility in model specification. For example, a
simple logistic growth function can be integrated as a resource
sub-model to replace the default resource
function.
logistic_res_mod <- function(X_0, K = 2000, gr = 1){
X_1 <- X_0 + gr * X_0 * ( 1 - X_0/K );
return(X_1);
}
sim <- gmse_apply(res_mod = logistic_res_mod, X_0 = 200, gr = 0.3, stakeholders = 5);
The gmse_apply
function
simulates a single GMSE time step, and therefore must be looped for
simulations over multiple time steps. Within loops, GMSE arguments can
be redefined to simulate changing conditions (e.g., change in policy
availability or stakeholder budgets, see Use of the
gmse_apply function and Advanced case study
options), thereby allowing many management scenarios to be simulated
in silico.
The GMSE package can be downloaded from CRAN (https://cran.r-project.org/package=GMSE) or GitHub (https://confoobio.github.io/gmse/). GMSE is open source under GNU Public License.
Here we have introduced the R package GMSE, software for modelling
social-ecological dynamics under scenarios of potential conflict. GMSE
provides a powerful tool for individual-based modelling simulations
while also allowing for extensive model customisation. GMSE vignettes
provide additional examples for getting started with gmse
or gmse_gui
for
simulations using default resource, observation, manager, and user
sub-models (Example case study in GMSE, Management frequency and extinction risk, and Adaptive timing of investment strategy), and for
using gmse_apply
for advanced model customisation (Use of the
gmse_apply function, Advanced case study
options, and Default GMSE data structures)
and integration with existing packages (e.g., Fisheries Library in R,
see Fisheries example integrating FLR). Future
versions of GMSE will include additional features and improve upon the
realism of social and ecological modelling components, while also
maintaining a high degree of flexibility and modulatarity for model
customisation.
This project was funded by the European Research Council under the European Union’s H2020/ERC grant agreement no. 679651 (ConFooBio) to NB. ABD is funded by a Leverhulme Trust Early Career Fellowship. We thank two anonymous reviewers for helpful comments.